Less Economic and Financial Market Volatilty With the Fed than Without

banking panics and recessions/depressions every decade a resounding success
Since we're doing logical fallacies, every decade beats the every 7 years mark under the FR.

Correlation does not imply causation!

I've come to the conclusion the libertarian/gold bug/Austrian convergence is little more than a political cargo cult based around mental midgets and reactionaries like Ron Paul and Lew Rockwell. I would hesitate to lump in the actual Austrian academics with this crowd, though.

There's also a White Nationalist/Neo-Nazi/911 truther/Austrian/gold bug convergence. You can find where they converge using some creative queries with The Google. :lol:
 
Last edited:
The Libertarians are extremely well funded and good at getting their propaganda out to those that would buy into it.
 
Correlation does not imply causation

The gold standard was a failure, unless you consider banking panics and recessions/depressions every decade a resounding success.

The FED has largely done a decent job, except for the Great Depression, which was a result of the gold standard.

And again, Correlation does not imply causation.

But this seems to be the MO around here regarding economics and history.

Embedded in your tit-for-tat with Kimura there is a useful point. I've always thought that economic reasoning rested on three legs: economic theory, economic data (econometrics), and economic history. In fact in graduate school you have to pass exams in each of these fields to become a degree candidate.

When anyone ignores any of the three, they risk some embarrassing results.

Tying the return to the gold standard in the Twenties to the Great Depression has been a well discussed episode in economic history. Keynes predicted the results in the "Economic Consequences of the Peace" (1919) and Milton Friedman's magna opus "Monetary History of the United States" devotes a lot of pages to it. In fact the connection is only minimally supported by the economic data, the real case is made by the historical record and economic theory. Our recent economic woes have lent new perspective on the effect of monetary policy in a financial crisis in a way not available since 1929 itself. This historical discussion and comparison to the "Lesser Depression" of today has been an immensely productive intellectual endeavor which I hope informs both theory and policy for the next century.
 
The Federal Reserve is not perfect but the ability to impact the money supply is one of the most powerful tools our economy has to maintain long term growth. If you are looking for causation then start with Milton Friedman's work concerning money supply.

Friedman was a card carrying liberal to some.
 
The gold standard was a failure, unless you consider banking panics and recessions/depressions every decade a resounding success.

The FED has largely done a decent job, except for the Great Depression, which was a result of the gold standard.

And again, Correlation does not imply causation.

But this seems to be the MO around here regarding economics and history.

Embedded in your tit-for-tat with Kimura there is a useful point. I've always thought that economic reasoning rested on three legs: economic theory, economic data (econometrics), and economic history. In fact in graduate school you have to pass exams in each of these fields to become a degree candidate.

When anyone ignores any of the three, they risk some embarrassing results.

Tying the return to the gold standard in the Twenties to the Great Depression has been a well discussed episode in economic history. Keynes predicted the results in the "Economic Consequences of the Peace" (1919) and Milton Friedman's magna opus "Monetary History of the United States" devotes a lot of pages to it. In fact the connection is only minimally supported by the economic data, the real case is made by the historical record and economic theory. Our recent economic woes have lent new perspective on the effect of monetary policy in a financial crisis in a way not available since 1929 itself. This historical discussion and comparison to the "Lesser Depression" of today has been an immensely productive intellectual endeavor which I hope informs both theory and policy for the next century.

One reason I cannot take von mises and Rand Paulian people seriously is they ignore the historical reality of what it meant when a holder of dollars could demand payment in gold, and the EFFECT of that on monetary supply and the price (not value) of gold. And that what would have meant in 2008.

And THAT should prove the op, even if one attempts to ignore Friedman.
 
One reason I cannot take von mises and Rand Paulian people seriously is they ignore the historical reality of what it meant when a holder of dollars could demand payment in gold, and the EFFECT of that on monetary supply and the price (not value) of gold. And that what would have meant in 2008.

:lmao:
 
Between 1880 and 1914, the period when the United States was on the “classical gold standard,” inflation averaged only 0.1 percent per year.
Right, and we know nobody planted a crop or built a factory in 1880 intending to sell the harvest or market the product thirty-four years later.
zblgcpiplus.jpg

We also know that 30% inflation one year and 20 deflation another is damned hard on running a farm or business. Bottom line si that the 1933 gold certificate recall is not about to be reversed any time soon.
 
And again, Correlation does not imply causation.

But this seems to be the MO around here regarding economics and history.

Embedded in your tit-for-tat with Kimura there is a useful point. I've always thought that economic reasoning rested on three legs: economic theory, economic data (econometrics), and economic history. In fact in graduate school you have to pass exams in each of these fields to become a degree candidate.

When anyone ignores any of the three, they risk some embarrassing results.

Tying the return to the gold standard in the Twenties to the Great Depression has been a well discussed episode in economic history. Keynes predicted the results in the "Economic Consequences of the Peace" (1919) and Milton Friedman's magna opus "Monetary History of the United States" devotes a lot of pages to it. In fact the connection is only minimally supported by the economic data, the real case is made by the historical record and economic theory. Our recent economic woes have lent new perspective on the effect of monetary policy in a financial crisis in a way not available since 1929 itself. This historical discussion and comparison to the "Lesser Depression" of today has been an immensely productive intellectual endeavor which I hope informs both theory and policy for the next century.

One reason I cannot take von mises and Rand Paulian people seriously is they ignore the historical reality of what it meant when a holder of dollars could demand payment in gold, and the EFFECT of that on monetary supply and the price (not value) of gold. And that what would have meant in 2008.

And THAT should prove the op, even if one attempts to ignore Friedman.

I think a certain segment of von Mises crowd wants a gold standard based on 100% reserves. I've read most of Rothbard's work on this subject, so I'm more than familiar with the literature, minus the intellectual circle jerk about the nature of the state.
 
Last edited:
Embedded in your tit-for-tat with Kimura there is a useful point. I've always thought that economic reasoning rested on three legs: economic theory, economic data (econometrics), and economic history. In fact in graduate school you have to pass exams in each of these fields to become a degree candidate.

When anyone ignores any of the three, they risk some embarrassing results.

Tying the return to the gold standard in the Twenties to the Great Depression has been a well discussed episode in economic history. Keynes predicted the results in the "Economic Consequences of the Peace" (1919) and Milton Friedman's magna opus "Monetary History of the United States" devotes a lot of pages to it. In fact the connection is only minimally supported by the economic data, the real case is made by the historical record and economic theory. Our recent economic woes have lent new perspective on the effect of monetary policy in a financial crisis in a way not available since 1929 itself. This historical discussion and comparison to the "Lesser Depression" of today has been an immensely productive intellectual endeavor which I hope informs both theory and policy for the next century.

One reason I cannot take von mises and Rand Paulian people seriously is they ignore the historical reality of what it meant when a holder of dollars could demand payment in gold, and the EFFECT of that on monetary supply and the price (not value) of gold. And that what would have meant in 2008.

And THAT should prove the op, even if one attempts to ignore Friedman.

I think a certain segment of von Mises crowd wants a gold standard based on 100% reserves. I've read most of Rothbard's work on this subject, so I'm more than familiar with the literature, minus the intellectual circle jerk about the nature of the state.

You are correct. I should not have lumped all the von mises folks in one pile. But the problem remains the same: if the options are to peg financial liquidy to a commodity that's price fluctuates because of politics, market assumptions of the strengh of the domestic economy, and supplies of the commodity that have no connenction to liquidity .... and Friedman, go with Uncle Milton everytime.
 
Two economic historians are quoted in this piece about how central banks came into being in response to financial crises.

... Central banks have been built on financial crises, with each major tremor expanding their role. And today's economic convulsions foreshadow more changes to come at the Fed.

If it wasn't for crises, central banks might not exist. In Britain, after years of civil war and the ouster of King James by William III in 1688, the country's public finances were in tatters, with tax collection falling short of what the government needed to pay its bills and lenders unsure about the stability of the government. The Bank of England, one of the first central banks and for centuries the most important one, was founded in 1694 to purchase government debt and curtail the funding crisis.

The establishment of the Bank of England came at the beginning of a great societal shift, when new ideas were challenging old doctrines, and rising world trade was giving new power to merchant classes. But the expansion in commerce and banking also made financial crises more prevalent. Speculative bubbles led to spectacular market crashes.

"The Bank of England received heavy criticism in many of the crises of the 19th century when it didn't act fast enough," says Rutgers University economic historian Michael Bordo. "It learned to be lender of last resort." ...

But for much of the 19th century and into the 20th, the U.S. had no central bank. Many Americans feared that nothing good could come from one bank wielding so much power. In 1816, a central bank to help fund government finances that had been badly depleted by the War of 1812 was established. In his 1832 veto of the extension of the bank's charter, President Andrew Jackson wrote that "Great evils...flow from such a concentration of power in the hands of a few men irresponsible to the people."

While financial crises in England diminished through the 19th century, they were a regular feature of American life.

"Crises are much more frequent when we don't have a central bank," says New York University Stern School economic historian Richard Sylla. With nobody willing to step into the fray when borrowers ran into trouble, small credit-market problems could easily spin into major ones.

The turning point came in 1907. The availability of credit was tight throughout the world that year, and that October, a speculative attempt to corner the stock of United Copper Co. failed. That sparked a run on the deposits of Knickerbocker Trust Co., which had helped fund the scheme, eventually leading to the firm's collapse. John Pierpont Morgan, the giant of American finance, took on the role of lender of last resort.

Struggling with a bad cold, sleep-deprived and sustaining himself with little more than cigars, Morgan put up millions of his firm's money to avert the crisis and cajoled other bankers into doing the same. In a famous incident, Morgan gathered a throng of bankers and trust executives in his library on the evening of Nov. 3, locking the doors and not opening them until 4:45 the next morning, after the men had agreed to take part in a $25 million loan.

The Panic of 1907 helped push aside longstanding worries over the economic power concentrated in an American central bank, and in 1913 the Federal Reserve Act was passed....

Central Banks Are Creatures of Financial Crises - WSJ.com
 
One reason I cannot take von mises and Rand Paulian people seriously is they ignore the historical reality of what it meant when a holder of dollars could demand payment in gold, and the EFFECT of that on monetary supply and the price (not value) of gold. And that what would have meant in 2008.

And THAT should prove the op, even if one attempts to ignore Friedman.

I think a certain segment of von Mises crowd wants a gold standard based on 100% reserves. I've read most of Rothbard's work on this subject, so I'm more than familiar with the literature, minus the intellectual circle jerk about the nature of the state.

You are correct. I should not have lumped all the von mises folks in one pile. But the problem remains the same: if the options are to peg financial liquidy to a commodity that's price fluctuates because of politics, market assumptions of the strengh of the domestic economy, and supplies of the commodity that have no connenction to liquidity .... and Friedman, go with Uncle Milton everytime.

Friedman supported QE.

The problem with the gold standard is that the money should grow with the economy. If money supply did not grow as the economy grew, it would tighten financial conditions, which would be unnecessary in the absence of inflation.

The gold proponents argue that as the price of money, i.e. gold, rises, more gold will be mined and the money supply will increase, loosening financial conditions. This is fine, in theory, and should apply over the long-term, but it does not take into account idiosyncrasies of other factors in the short or intermediate term. For example, for nearly 11 years after the bottom of gold market at the beginning of 1999, mined gold supply contracted, even though the price of gold went from $250 to north of $1500. That shouldn't happen in a market without frictions.

But there are frictions in the real world that make gold supply problematic in response to fluctuations in the economy over the near to intermediate term. For example, it takes 7-8 years for new mines to come online given how long it takes to go through the environmental process, hearings, political approval, etc. Gold's investment cycle is no different than any other commodity cycle.

I'm not necessarily sanguine about this giant fiat monetary experiment we are undertaking. That currencies have been totally free of gold for 40+ years does not mean it's successful. The Soviet Union existed for 70 years, and not many think it was a success to emulate. But on the other hand, a gold standard as the basis for a monetary system is deeply flawed.
 
I own this book but haven't read it. I think I will soon.

The Depression was exceptional in its economic ferocity. As Liaquat Ahamed writes in his book "Lords of Finance": "During a three-year period, real GDP [gross domestic product] in the major economies fell by over 25 percent, a quarter of the adult male population was thrown out of work. . . . The economic turmoil created hardships in every corner of the globe, from the prairies of Canada to the teeming cities of Asia."

Anyone who wants to know why should read this engrossing book. Ahamed, a professional money manager, attributes the Depression to two central causes: the misguided restoration of the gold standard in the 1920s and the massive inter-governmental debts, including German reparations, resulting from World War I.

His story builds on the scholarship of economists Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, Charles Kindleberger, Barry Eichengreen and Peter Temin. But Ahamed excels in evoking the political and personal forces that led to disaster. His title refers to four men deeply implicated in the era's perverse policies: Montagu Norman, governor of the Bank of England; Benjamin Strong, head of the New York Federal Reserve Bank; Émile Moreau, head of the Banque de France; and Hjalmar Schacht, head of Germany's Reichsbank. Their determination to reinstate the gold standard -- seen as necessary for global prosperity -- brought ruin.

Under the gold standard, paper money was backed by gold reserves. If gold flowed into a country (normally from a trade surplus or a foreign loan), its money and credit supply were supposed to expand. If gold flowed out, money and credit were supposed to contract. During World War I, Europe's governments suspended the gold standard. They financed the war with paper money and loans from America. The appeal of restoring the gold standard was that it would instill confidence by making paper money trustworthy.

Unfortunately, the war damaged the system beyond repair. Britain, the key country, was left with only 7.5 percent of the world's gold reserves in 1925. Together, the United States and France held more than half the world's gold. The war had expanded U.S. reserves, and when France returned to gold, it did so with an undervalued exchange rate that boosted exports and gold reserves. Meanwhile, German reparations to Britain and France were massive, while those countries owed huge amounts to the United States. The global financial system was so debt-laden that it "cracked at the first pressure," writes Ahamed.

That came after a rise in American interest rates in 1928 forced other countries to follow (no one wanted to lose gold by having investors shift funds elsewhere) and ultimately led to the 1929 stock market crash. As economies weakened, debts went into default. Bank panics ensued. Credit and industrial production declined. Unemployment rose. Weakness fed on weakness.

washingtonpost.com
 
And one more, just for good measure.

As countries abandoned the gold standard during the Depression, they began to grow again. The longer countries waited to leave the gold standard, the longer they waited for growth to resume.

Barry Eichengreen pointed out years ago that major economies went off gold in the following order: Japan, Britain, Germany, US, France. [... the correlation between going off gold and recovery is in fact perfect] And here’s what happened to their industrial output:

gd_recovery.png

Modified goldbugism at the WSJ - Paul Krugman Blog - NYTimes.com
 
And one more, just for good measure.

As countries abandoned the gold standard during the Depression, they began to grow again. The longer countries waited to leave the gold standard, the longer they waited for growth to resume.

Barry Eichengreen pointed out years ago that major economies went off gold in the following order: Japan, Britain, Germany, US, France. [... the correlation between going off gold and recovery is in fact perfect] And here’s what happened to their industrial output:

gd_recovery.png

Modified goldbugism at the WSJ - Paul Krugman Blog - NYTimes.com

The gold standard (like most other fx regimes) also means that the interest rates are ultimately set by the market. Ultimately, as you pointed out, government spending is directly constrained by the amount of gold reserves backing said currency (historically, during times of war, most nations abandoned the gold standard). Since gold reserves are mostly steady and not increasing during the short term, this results in government spending being limited to a tax and borrow scenario. This is what I try to explain to the gold bug crowd all the time. This where the term "printing money" comes from, because if the government desires to deficit spend, it risks said $$$$ through printing and getting cashed in for teh gold.

Government borrowing under this scenario mitigates the risk through preventing immediate conversion rights until this borrowing matures so to speak, and the government is basically competing to convert. The holders of gold certificates under this scenario can a) purchase Treasury securities or b) convert to gold. I should also mention that historically under an fx regime government borrowing costs have skyrocketed into triple digits. Government usually got the shit end of the stick due to the curve shooting up in a vertical fashion reinforcing the point that no rate of interest can prevent currency holders from desiring to convert in the end.
 
Last edited:
Correlation does not imply causation

The gold standard was a failure, unless you consider banking panics and recessions/depressions every decade a resounding success.

Borat_Great_Success.jpg


The FED has largely done a decent job, except for the Great Depression, which was a result of the gold standard.

There is nothing wrong with Depressions or recessions. There is a problem when a nation obtains incredible debt and claims success despite a never ending stimulus. A recession in a less regulated non stimulated market clears it's debts and comes out stronger than before, an economy that is based on bubble building by the Government is doomed in the long term. All predictions of what the FED-R would do to destroy the nation have come true.

17 trillion in debt and no end in sight. People can claim success but it has taken 100 years to dig a hole so big no one even wants to pretend to try and get out of it.
 
I own this book but haven't read it. I think I will soon.

The Depression was exceptional in its economic ferocity. As Liaquat Ahamed writes in his book "Lords of Finance": "During a three-year period, real GDP [gross domestic product] in the major economies fell by over 25 percent, a quarter of the adult male population was thrown out of work. . . . The economic turmoil created hardships in every corner of the globe, from the prairies of Canada to the teeming cities of Asia."

Anyone who wants to know why should read this engrossing book. Ahamed, a professional money manager, attributes the Depression to two central causes: the misguided restoration of the gold standard in the 1920s and the massive inter-governmental debts, including German reparations, resulting from World War I.

His story builds on the scholarship of economists Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, Charles Kindleberger, Barry Eichengreen and Peter Temin. But Ahamed excels in evoking the political and personal forces that led to disaster. His title refers to four men deeply implicated in the era's perverse policies: Montagu Norman, governor of the Bank of England; Benjamin Strong, head of the New York Federal Reserve Bank; Émile Moreau, head of the Banque de France; and Hjalmar Schacht, head of Germany's Reichsbank. Their determination to reinstate the gold standard -- seen as necessary for global prosperity -- brought ruin.

Under the gold standard, paper money was backed by gold reserves. If gold flowed into a country (normally from a trade surplus or a foreign loan), its money and credit supply were supposed to expand. If gold flowed out, money and credit were supposed to contract. During World War I, Europe's governments suspended the gold standard. They financed the war with paper money and loans from America. The appeal of restoring the gold standard was that it would instill confidence by making paper money trustworthy.

Unfortunately, the war damaged the system beyond repair. Britain, the key country, was left with only 7.5 percent of the world's gold reserves in 1925. Together, the United States and France held more than half the world's gold. The war had expanded U.S. reserves, and when France returned to gold, it did so with an undervalued exchange rate that boosted exports and gold reserves. Meanwhile, German reparations to Britain and France were massive, while those countries owed huge amounts to the United States. The global financial system was so debt-laden that it "cracked at the first pressure," writes Ahamed.

That came after a rise in American interest rates in 1928 forced other countries to follow (no one wanted to lose gold by having investors shift funds elsewhere) and ultimately led to the 1929 stock market crash. As economies weakened, debts went into default. Bank panics ensued. Credit and industrial production declined. Unemployment rose. Weakness fed on weakness.

washingtonpost.com

I'm sorry... If I understand your quote the debt was created due to fake money, then the blame was shifted to gold when a country spent more than they could re pay?

Basically it sounds like someone wanted a limitless CC, got it.... lived far outside of what they could afford, grew (invested) into projects they would never be able to repay then blamed Gold.

if they were forced to live within their means by money backed by something real, the depression could have been avoided or dramatically reduced in time.
 
There is nothing wrong with Depressions or recessions.

There's huge problem with depression and recessions, especially the human and social costs, in addition to being on the receiving end of a deflationary spiral.

There is a problem when a nation obtains incredible debt and claims success despite a never ending stimulus. A recession in a less regulated non stimulated market clears it's debts and comes out stronger than before, an economy that is based on bubble building by the Government is doomed in the long term. All predictions of what the FED-R would do to destroy the nation have come true.

Well...that's just inaccurate. Please explain how the FED has destroyed the nation. How many panics have we had since we abandoned the gold standard?

17 trillion in debt and no end in sight. People can claim success but it has taken 100 years to dig a hole so big no one even wants to pretend to try and get out of it.

It's not the same as household debt. US public debt represents the total savings of the private sector and its propensity to save. We're talking about dollar deposits over at the FED at the end of the day. The government doesn't ever have to run down its stock of debt if it so chooses.
 
Last edited:
I own this book but haven't read it. I think I will soon.

The Depression was exceptional in its economic ferocity. As Liaquat Ahamed writes in his book "Lords of Finance": "During a three-year period, real GDP [gross domestic product] in the major economies fell by over 25 percent, a quarter of the adult male population was thrown out of work. . . . The economic turmoil created hardships in every corner of the globe, from the prairies of Canada to the teeming cities of Asia."

Anyone who wants to know why should read this engrossing book. Ahamed, a professional money manager, attributes the Depression to two central causes: the misguided restoration of the gold standard in the 1920s and the massive inter-governmental debts, including German reparations, resulting from World War I.

His story builds on the scholarship of economists Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, Charles Kindleberger, Barry Eichengreen and Peter Temin. But Ahamed excels in evoking the political and personal forces that led to disaster. His title refers to four men deeply implicated in the era's perverse policies: Montagu Norman, governor of the Bank of England; Benjamin Strong, head of the New York Federal Reserve Bank; Émile Moreau, head of the Banque de France; and Hjalmar Schacht, head of Germany's Reichsbank. Their determination to reinstate the gold standard -- seen as necessary for global prosperity -- brought ruin.

Under the gold standard, paper money was backed by gold reserves. If gold flowed into a country (normally from a trade surplus or a foreign loan), its money and credit supply were supposed to expand. If gold flowed out, money and credit were supposed to contract. During World War I, Europe's governments suspended the gold standard. They financed the war with paper money and loans from America. The appeal of restoring the gold standard was that it would instill confidence by making paper money trustworthy.

Unfortunately, the war damaged the system beyond repair. Britain, the key country, was left with only 7.5 percent of the world's gold reserves in 1925. Together, the United States and France held more than half the world's gold. The war had expanded U.S. reserves, and when France returned to gold, it did so with an undervalued exchange rate that boosted exports and gold reserves. Meanwhile, German reparations to Britain and France were massive, while those countries owed huge amounts to the United States. The global financial system was so debt-laden that it "cracked at the first pressure," writes Ahamed.

That came after a rise in American interest rates in 1928 forced other countries to follow (no one wanted to lose gold by having investors shift funds elsewhere) and ultimately led to the 1929 stock market crash. As economies weakened, debts went into default. Bank panics ensued. Credit and industrial production declined. Unemployment rose. Weakness fed on weakness.

washingtonpost.com

I'm sorry... If I understand your quote the debt was created due to fake money, then the blame was shifted to gold when a country spent more than they could re pay?

Basically it sounds like someone wanted a limitless CC, got it.... lived far outside of what they could afford, grew (invested) into projects they would never be able to repay then blamed Gold.

if they were forced to live within their means by money backed by something real, the depression could have been avoided or dramatically reduced in time.

What in god's name is fake money? The dollar is legal tender for all debts public and private.

Newsflash: the government has an unlimited credit card. It even sets the interest rate at which it "borrows". And the government can always services it debt. It's a matter of shifting funds from Treasuries to reserve accounts. How is this a problem?

We're actually living WAY below our means.
 
Last edited:
Less Economic and Financial Market Volatilty With the Fed than Without

well, of course, every knows that
 

Forum List

Back
Top